Light notes on Hodgson’s seminal Work: The venture of Islam--- Economic Hegemony as an impetus of modern Imperialism: is it over?
In today's reading, Hodgson chronicles the historical background that ultimately
gave way to the World Order that prevailed in the 19th century and
which continues, at least in its broad lines, to dominate. Nineteenth century
was by all accounts a European century. The century saw the West, mostly
Europe, but America as well, asserting its superiority on the international
scene, extending its sovereignty through both economic and military means.
During much of the 19th century, European vessels and other maritime
equipments crisscrossed the world oceans unchallenged. At no prior point in
history had the Europeans enjoyed such freedom at sea. The Muslim world, which
had once stood as the strong neighbor and contender, was at the receiving end
of this new relentless campaign of world conquest. The march through
Muslim lands would continue unabated until the second decade of the 20th
century. During this period lands were divided between and annexed by invading
armies, allowing for borders to be drawn—even when no hint of breakage exited
hitherto as Hodgson rightly remarked: “The European made a great point of
inventing boundaries where they did not exist.” [227] Tracing the history of
European domination of the world inevitably leads to the discussion of the
methods employed to bring others under this hegemony and also others’ reaction
to them.
Hodgson
is right in pointing out that reactions to the new role of the West were quick
and took various forms. First, attempts were made to repel the encroaching
armies, but this was soon proven futile because of the apparent disparity in
technical, especially military, means. The second stage was a period of
accommodation, an attempt at appeasement in exchange for certain commercial and
economic rights for the elites in various Muslim societies. Western imperialism
was not initially militaristic in nature, although its military might would
become central for hosts of reasons. Imperialism was mostly driven by economic
interests. When it started it had two main goals in mind. First, it was meant
to find new markets for Western companies which were producing at a massive
scale thanks to the industrial revolution. Second, it was also meant in the
same vein to secure natural resources and raw materials to fuel this very
revolution. As a result, economy played a major role. A good example of
the role of economy in the imperial enterprise is Egypt. As Hodgson notes, it
was on the pretext that Egypt failed to meet its financial obligations (which
was created by Western lenders who knew well that Egypt can’t sustain, given
the prospect of the international market, its spending spree, yet continued to
lend it). The use of fiscal institutions to create a state of dependency
is also pursued elsewhere with the Ottoman Empire. Even though the Ottoman’s
inability to repay their debts did not translate into direct military
occupation, their dependency allowed European countries to intervene in the
Empire’s most intimate affairs.
The
larger community mostly suffered and silently resented the new order. The
discontent among the masses, which only grew over time, lent itself to more
matured forms of resistance. The new forms of resistance were championed by
nationalist movements which sought to use Western tools and concepts to uproot
Western hegemony. That these movements were eventually successful in creating
‘modern’ states in Asia, North Africa and the Middle East is not a matter of
question. However, the question of the extent to which these states were able
to address the essential conditions that made of 19th century a
special European century was a different story. The answer to this question
lies in providing a comparative reading of the current World Order and the one
that prevailed during the 19th century. To the extent that they have
differed, a positive answer could be given. An assessment of this sort has to
probe two areas: the ability of such states to bridge the technical gap that
brought about the initial onslaught and the resultant state of economic
dependency on one hand, and their ability to fully absorb and thoroughly
integrate the concepts that at once constituted the priori and posteriori of
modernity.
One
can safely assert that the technical parity is far from accomplished and the
gap in this regard, has only widened, not narrowed. While points can be
made about certain improvement on the technical sphere in some Muslim countries
such as Pakistan, India and Malaysia, this technical improvement are still a
far cry from development in Europe and elsewhere in the world. Even in most
third world countries, the technical gap is still significant. The exception to
this being India and China, with the latter narrowing this gap in much faster
pace in more than one domain and the former advancing in some areas such as
computer programming and nuclear power. One will also find the question
about the integration of the concepts of modernity to be more complex for a
number of reasons. Modernity in of itself has no clear cut definition. Still
even if one is to provide a workable definition, the subjective nature of evaluating
to what extent a concept, an outlook is culturally integrated would still
preclude the arrival at a satisfactory conclusion. If by modern concepts one
means the tendency of state and private institutions to employ rational and
scientific reasoning (with whatever subjective limitations one can attach to these
two) in the running of their everyday affair, one would still have to answer to
what end is such rational and scientific reasoning is used. More problematic,
is the fact that a varnish of modernity, a display of rationality and
scientific research can hide behind it an emotional and impressionistic modus
operandi. The ease with which certain technical gadgets could be
transferred from one place to another facilitated and improved the art of
camouflage, the act of self-deception. Part of this self-deception is that most
of these countries (I am speaking here about Muslim countries specifically, but
this also true of large numbers of African and Asian countries as well) did not
adopt modernity out of genuine desire, but as a necessity—as reality
imposed by foreign entity. Therefore, modernity is integrated only as much as
is necessary to convince others that it had been realized. The fact that the
West has, in general, no desire to see the core of modernity successfully
implanted elsewhere (because of the possible implications of that to the world
order) made this process of self-deception easy for the ‘dependent’ and a
self-fulfilling prophecy on the part of the West. Again with the exception of
China, the prevalence of modernity in the above sense is still limited to small
segment of the economy and of the population in most third world countries.
Unlike
the question of technical parity and integration of modernity, the disparity on
the economic level and the mechanism to perpetuate it is still (very much) in
place. A modicum of hope materialized after the wave of decolonization
succeeded in giving many elites in third world countries the chance to steer
their countries in the direction of full independence. But a combination of
planning on the part of the West and inefficacy of most of these regimes
contributed to aborting that dream. The lion’s share of shattering hopes of
economic dependency was taken by the institutions of Briton Woods, especially
World Bank and the International Monetary Fundy. These institutions first
assured the dependency by making available to state who became newly
independent a high interest-based loan packages along with some sound, but not
always serious or sincere policy advice. This phase led to accumulated debts
and inevitably to these institutions taking a far more aggressive role in
dictating the fiscal policies of these countries. The word Structural
adjustments, which became a buzzword in the early 1990s, was the magic
word for a process that led to wild policies of deregulations and ultimately to
the shrinkage of the public sector in favor of the private sector, especially
multinational corporations. Now, this may not be a European hegemony in the way
that 19th century imperialism was, but it is, indeed, a hegemony of
multinational corporations most of which were until very recently based in and
operated from the West. Now with the rise of outsourcing, the industrial
base and unskilled labor, not necessarily the ownership or the skilled human
capital, has somewhat shifted.
تعليقات
إرسال تعليق